Trump’s current trade strategy will diminish American power and American technological capability, divide the U.S. from allies and partners, and give China an opening to become the world’s preeminent nation. I still think it’s unlikely that this is intentional; there’s an old adage that you should “never attribute to malice that which is adequately explained by stupidity.” The haphazard, last-minute, on-again-off-again way that Trump and his team have rolled out their tariff policy, and the fact that Congress has not chosen to use its power to revoke the President’s tariff authority, suggests that stupidity is the main factor in play here. But in any case, there are obviously some people within the Trump administration and the MAGA movement who would like Trump to produce a trade strategy that helps to contain Chinese power. CEA Chair Stephen Miran has written that “China has chosen to double down on its mercantilist, export-led model to secure marginal income, much to the rest of the world’s consternation.” And Treasury Secretary Scott Bessent went even further, suggesting that containment of China should be the main goal of U.S. trade policy:
This is actually a very realistic goal. Every day that Trump’s tariff chaos makes the U.S. look like a chaotic clown car makes it a less realistic goal, but as of right now, I still think that it would be possible for the U.S. to radically pivot its trade and industrial policies in order to create a coalition of nations that could economically balance, compete with, and even isolate China. And it’s not too hard to imagine what that strategy would look like. But first, we should think about why we would want to economically pressure China, and what we might hope to accomplish. After all, in an ideal world, countries simply trade with each other and get rich, instead of fighting. And China has plenty of good stuff to offer the world — cool cars, cheap solar panels and batteries, and lots more. Why should we take an adversarial approach to trade with China? The reason is geopolitics. Singing hymns to the gains from trade doesn’t change the fact that for whatever reason, the leaders of powerful countries sometimes want to dominate or even attack other nations. The world is an ungoverned place, and the balance of power is the only thing that keeps the peace. Currently, China has become the world’s preeminent manufacturing nation. Its current leaders also think of the U.S. and many of its allies as either rivals or outright enemies. They appear determined to conquer Taiwan, carve off pieces of India, Japan, and the Philippines, and generally use Chinese power to dominate smaller countries. It makes sense to want to weaken China’s ability to do all this, while strengthening the other nations’ capacities to resist it. The goals of trade policy with China should therefore probably include the following:
That doesn’t mean that prosperity and cool cars shouldn’t be goals of China trade policy, but merely that they should be augmented with these other geopolitical goals. In any case, when I talk about economically “containing” China, that’s what I’m talking about. So here’s a list of things we would do if we were serious about that goal. Obviously this list is very, very far away from anything the Trump administration is doing or contemplating. But this is what I think it would take. Zero trade barriers with any nations other than ChinaManufacturers need scale to drive down costs and remain competitive. One reason China’s manufacturers are so formidable — and why American manufacturers were so formidable relative to their rivals 80 years ago — is that they have access to a huge domestic market. Chinese car companies like BYD can sell untold numbers of cars to their billion consumers; this allows those companies to scale up and drive down costs to levels no foreign competitor can match. BYD is currently building a single factory that’s bigger than the city of San Francisco. Another key factor that makes Chinese manufacturers so powerful is domestic supply chains. Practically everything that goes into a Chinese EV, particularly the battery, the metal, and the chips, is produced in-country. That makes it very quick and easy for Chinese manufacturers to source everything they need, instead of having to struggle to import it from overseas. It’s inherently very hard for American manufacturers can match those two advantages. The U.S. is much smaller than China — our consumption is larger in dollar terms, but we have far fewer people, and so our companies can’t ship as many units domestically. Chinese people buy about double the number of cars every year that Americans do. Of course this problem is even more acute for America’s allies, like Japan and Korea. Smaller countries compensate by finding highly specialized niches to be competitive in. But this leaves their supply chains and defense-industrial bases at a disadvantage; China, because it’s so huge, can more easily create a fully self-sufficient manufacturing ecosystem (which it has, in fact, spent the last two decades trying to do). The only possible solution way for China’s rivals to match it in size is to gang up. And in this case, what “gang up” means is to form a free trade zone amongst each other, with zero trade barriers between them. If the U.S. had zero trade barriers with Europe, Japan, Korea, India, and the countries of Southeast Asia, those countries wouldn’t become exactly like one huge “domestic” market. There would still be language barriers, geographic distance, exchange rate fluctuations, and national regulatory differences that end up accidentally restricting trade. But it would go a long way toward allowing American manufacturers — and European, Japanese, Korean, Indian, and Southeast Asian manufacturers — to attain the sort of economies of scale and supply-chain networks that China enjoys within its borders. Basically, to balance China, you’d need to start thinking of “Non-China” as a single vast economic entity. If this sounds familiar, well, it should. Two trade treaties, the TPP with Asia and the TTIP with Europe, would have gone a long way toward creating this sort of common market among non-Chinese manufacturing nations. Both were killed by Donald Trump. But in any case, if you want to economically balance China and reduce economic dependence on China, this is the first thing you’d do. Tariffs on Chinese intermediate goods, and data collection on supply chainsThe next thing you’d need to deal with is supply chain vulnerabilities among non-Chinese nations. The ideal would be to make sure that Non-China has the ability to make everything it needs to make, so that A) Non-China can be self-sufficient in case of a major war, and B) China can’t dominate the nations of Non-China by exerting pressure on key supply chain vulnerabilities (like it’s doing right now with rare earths). One thing you need here is targeted protectionism. The idea is to prevent China from being able to put Non-China manufacturers out of business with a sudden flood of subsidized exports. For example, suppose China decided to destroy the American, Japanese, Korean, and Taiwanese chip industries by unleashing a massive flood of subsidized computer chips. The only way to prevent this strategy from working is protectionism. So you need the ability to put up targeted trade barriers very quickly, in sectors that China is making a bid to conquer. Note that this is very different from Trump’s tariff policy — it’s far more targeted in terms of industries, it’s only on China, and it has nothing to do with trade deficits or other macro imbalances. It’s more like the tariffs Biden put on some Chinese products. But there’s a problem here, which is that standard tariffs don’t hit intermediate goods. If China makes a phone, takes it apart, then ships the pieces to Vietnam, where Vietnamese workers snap it back together and sell it to America, our tariffs think that this phone is “made in Vietnam”. If laptops made in Mexico and sold in America contain Chinese chips, those chips aren’t subject to the tariff rate on Chinese goods — they’re only subject to the tariff rate on Mexican goods. Stephen Miran recognizes this fact in his 2024 note.¹ The solution to this is to apply tariffs not based on the country where something was finally assembled, but to the countries where the value was added. Doing this would allow us to put tariffs on Chinese intermediate goods like computer chips and batteries, in addition to final goods like phones and cars. Of course, applying tariffs in this way would require much better data collection. We’d need to figure out where the components in each imported good originated. This would require, among other things, a small army of bureaucrats. Industrial policy for strategic industriesIn order to give Non-China a self-sufficient, robust manufacturing ecosystem, we’d need to do a lot more than just stop China from poking new holes in that ecosystem. We’d have to fix the existing holes as well. For example, China already makes most of the world’s batteries and processes most of the world’s rare earths. Those are vulnerabilities that need to be dealt with. The way to do that is industrial policy — we need to start making things that we currently don’t make (or that we make very little of). Maybe given the right long-term incentives, those industries would reappear in Non-China on their own, but giving them a helping hand fixes the problem much more quickly. And sometimes, industrial policy can help create robustness within Non-China as wel |